Sunday, December 8, 2019

Capital Asset Prices a Theory of Market Equilibrium Under Conditions of Risk free essay sample

American Finance Association Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk Author(s): William F. Sharpe Source: The Journal of Finance, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Sep. , 1964), pp. 425-442 Published by: Blackwell Publishing for the American Finance Association Stable URL: http://www. jstor. org/stable/2977928 . Accessed: 23/08/2011 00:15 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms Conditions of Use, available at . http://www. jstor. org/page/info/about/policies/terms. sp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [emailprotected] org. Blackwell Publishing and American Finance Association are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Jou rnal of Finance. http://www. jstor. org The VOL. XIX journal of FINANCE No. 3 SEPTEMBER 1964 CAPITAL ASSET PRICES: A THEORY OF MARKET EQUILIBRIUM UNDER CONDITIONS OF RISK* WILLIAM F. SHARPEt I. INTRODUCTION ONE OF THE PROBLEMSwhich has plagued those attempting to predict the behavior of capital markets is the absence of a body of positive microeconomic theory dealing with conditions of risk. Although many useful insights can be obtained from the traditional models of investment under conditions of certainty, the pervasive influence of risk in financial transactions has forced those working in this area to adopt models of price behavior which are little more than assertions. A typical classroom explanation of the determination of capital asset prices, for example, usually begins with a careful and relatively rigorous description of the process through which individual preferences and physical relationships interact to determine an equilibriumpure interest rate. This is generally followed by the assertion that somehow a market risk-premium is also determined,with the prices of assets adjusting accordingly to account for differencesin their risk. A useful representation of the view of the capital market implied in such discussions is illustrated in Figure 1. In equilibrium, capital asset prices have adjusted so that the investor, if he follows rational procedures (primarily diversification), is able to attain any desired point along a capital market line. He may obtain a higher expected rate of return on his holdings only by incurring additional risk. In effect, the market presents him with two prices: the price of time, or the pure interest rate (shown by the intersection of the line with the horizontal axis) and the price of risk, the additional expected return per unit of risk borne (the reciprocal of the slope of the line). A great many people provided comments on early versions of this paper which led to major improvementsin the exposition. In addition to the referees, who were most helpful, the author wishes to express his appreciation to Dr. Harry Markowitz of the RAND Corporation,Professor Jack Hirshleifer of the University of California at Los Angeles, and to Professors Yoram Barzel, George Brabb, Bruce Johnson, Walter Oi and R . Haney Scott of the University of Washington. AssociateProfessorof Operations Research,Universityof Washington. 1. Althoughsome discussionsare also consistentwith a non-linear (but monotonic) curve. 425 426 The Journalof Finance At present there is no theory describing the manner in which the price of risk results from the basic influences of investor preferences, the physical attributes of capital assets, etc. Moreover, lacking such a theory, it is difficult to give any real meaning to the relationship between the price of a single asset and its risk. Through diversification, some of the risk inherent in an asset can be avoided so that its total risk is obviously not the relevant influence on its price; unfortunately little has been said concerning the particular risk component which is relevant. Risk Capital Market Line 0 Expected Rate of Return Pure InterestRate FIGURE 1 In the last ten years a number of economists have developed normative models dealing with asset choice under conditions of risk. Markowitz,2 following Von Neumann and Morgenstern, developed an analysis based on the expected utility maxim and proposed a general solution for the portfolio selection problem. Tobin showed that under certain conditions Markowitzs model implies that the process of investment choice can be broken down into two phases: first, the choice of a unique optimum combinationof risky assets; and second, a separate choice concerningthe allocation of funds between such a combination and a single riskless 2. Harry M. Markowitz, Portfolio Selection, Efficient Diversification of Investments (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc. , 1959). The major elements of the theory first appearedin his article Portfolio Selection,The Journal of Finance, XII (March 1952), 77-91. 3. James Tobin, Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk, The Review of Economic Studies, XXV (February, 1958), 65-86. CapitalAssetPrices 427 asset. Recently, Hicks4 has used a model similar to that proposed by Tobin to derive corresponding conclusions about individual investor behavior, dealing somewhat more explicitly with the nature of the conditions under which the process of investment choice can be dichotomized. An even more detailed discussion of this process, including a rigorous proof in the context of a choice among lotteries has been presented by Gordonand Gangolli. Although all the authors cited use virtually the same model of investor behavior,6 none has yet attempted to extend it to construct a market equilibriumtheory of asset prices under conditions of risk. We will show that such an extension provides a theory with implications consistent with the assertions of traditional financial theory described above. Moreover, it sheds considerable light on the relationship b etween the price of an asset and the various components of its overall risk. For these reasons it warrants considerationas a model of the determinationof capital asset prices. Part II provides the model of individual investor behavior under conditions of risk. In Part III the equilibrium conditions for the capital market are considered and the capital market line derived. The implications for the relationship between the prices of individual capital assets and the various components of risk are described in Part IV. II. OPTIMAL INVESTMENT POLICY FOR THE INDIVIDUAL The Investors Preference Function Assume that an individual views the outcome of any investment in probabilistic terms; that is, he thinks of the possible results in terms of some probability distribution. In assessing the desirability of a particular investment, however, he is willing to act on the basis of only two para4. John R. Hicks, Liquidity,The Economic Journal, LXXII (December, 1962), 787802. 5. M. J. Gordon and Ramesh Gangolli, Choice Among and Scale of Play on Lottery Type Alternatives, College of Business Administration,University of Rochester, 1962. For another discussion of this relationship see W. F. Sharpe, A Simplified Model for Portfolio Analysis, Management Science, Vol. 9, No. 2 (January 1963), 277-293. A related discussioncan be found in F. Modiglianiand M. H. Miller, The Cost of Capital, CorporationFinance, and the Theory of Investment, The AmericanEconomic Review, XLVIII (June 1958), 261-297. 6. Recently Hirshleifer has suggested that the mean-variance approach used in the articles cited is best regarded as a special case of a more general formulation due to -Arrow. See Hirshleifers InvestmentDecision Under Uncertainty,Papers and Proceedings of the Seventy-Sixth Annual Meeting of the AmericanEconomic Association, Dec. 963, or ArrowsLe Role des ValeursBoursierespour la Repartitionla Meilleuredes Risques, InternationalColloquiumon Econometrics,1952. 7. After preparingthis paper the author learned that Mr. Jack L. Treynor, of Arthur D. Little, Inc. , had independentlydeveloped a model similar in many respects to the one describedhere. UnfortunatelyMr. Treynors excellent work on this subject is, at present, unpublished. 428 The Journal of Finance meters of this distribution-its expec ted value and standard deviation. This can be representedby a total utility function of the form: U = f(E,, a,) where Ew indicates expected future wealth and cw the predicted standard deviation of the possible divergence of actual future wealth from Ew. Investors are assumed to prefer a higher expected future wealth to a lower value, ceteris paribus (dU/dEw 0). Moreover, they exhibit risk-aversion, choosing an investment offering a lower value of aw to one with a greater level, given the level of Ew (dU/dow 0). These assumptions imply that indifference curves relating Ew and co will be upward-sloping. To simplify the analysis, we assume that an investor has decided to commit a given amount (WI) of his present wealth to investment. Letting Wt be his terminal wealth and R the rate of return on his investment: R we have Wt R WI + Wi. This relationship makes it possible to express the investors utility in terms of R, since terminal wealth is directly related to the rate of return: U = g(ER, OR) . Figure 2 summarizes the model of investor preferences in a family of indifference curves; successive curves indicate higher levels of utility as one moves down and/or to the right. 10 8. Under certain conditions the mean-variance approach can be shown to lead to unsatisfactory predictions of behavior. Markowitz suggests that a model based on the semi-variance(the averageof the squareddeviationsbelow the mean) would be preferable; in light of the formidablecomputationalproblems,however, he bases his analysis on the variance and standard deviation. are 9. While only these characteristics requiredfor the analysis, it is generally assumed that the curves have the property of diminishingmarginal rates of substitution between EW and aw, as do those in our diagrams. 10. Such indifferencecurves can also be derived by assuming that the investor wishes to maximize expected utility and that his total utility can be representedby a quadratic function of R with decreasingmarginal utility. Both Markowitz and Tobin present such a derivation. A similar approachis used by Donald E. Farrar in The Investment Decision Under Uncertainty (Prentice-Hall, 1962). Unfortunately Farrar makes an error in his cardinal utility axioms to transderivation; he appeals to the Von-Neumann-Morgenstern form a function of the form: E(U) = a+ bER cER2 -CR2 into one of the form: E (U) = k1 E -k2aR2. Wt WI Wi is That such a transformation not consistent with the axioms can readily be seen in this form, since the first equation implies non-linear indifferencecurves in the ER aR2 plane while the second implies a linear relationship. Obviously no three (different) points can lie on both a line and a non-linear curve (with a monotonic derivative). Thus the two functions must imply different orderings among alternative choices in at least some instance. Capital Asset Prices 429 CYR // -7.. /he or .. Ineten poruiy The~. uv Thsetofinvestmentopportuniti ureshtoewihmsm shsuiiy Every investment plan available to him may be representedby a point in the ER, OR plane. If all such plans involve some risk, the area composed of such points will have an appearance similar to that shown in Figure 2. The investor will choose from among all possible plans the one placing him on the indifference curve representing the highest level of utility (point F). The decision can be made in two stages: first, find the set of efficient investment plans and, second choose one from among this set. A plan is said to be efficient if (and only if) there is no alternative with either (1) the same ER and a lower CR, (2) the same OR and a higher EB Thus investment Z is inefficientsince or (3) a higher ER and a lower CR. investments B, C, and D (among others) dominate it. The only plans which would be chosen must lie along the lower right-hand boundary (AFBDCX)- the investment opportunity curve. To understand the nature of this curve, consider two investment plans -A and B, each including one or more assets. Their predicted expected values and standard deviations of rate of return are shown in Figure 3. 430 The Journal of Finance If the proportion a of the individuals wealth is placed in plan A and the remainder (1-a) in B, the expected rate of return of the combinationwill lie between the expected returns of the two plans: ER= aERa + (1 a) ERb The predicted standard deviation of return of the combination is: RC Va2Ra 2 + (1 a)2 Rb2 + 2rab a(1 a) CRaORb Note that this relationshipincludes rab, the correlation coefficientbetween the predicted rates of return of the two investment plans. A value of +1 would indicate an investors belief that there is a precise positive relationship between the outcomes of the two investments. A zero value would indicate a belief that the outcomes of the two investments are completely independent and -1 that the investor feels that there is a precise inverse relationship between them. In the usual case rab will have a value between o and +1. Figure 3 shows the possible values of ERc and ORCobtainable with differentcombinations of A and B under two different assumptions about OR aRb -B CRa- I l I ERa FIGURE 3 I I I ERb ER CapitalAssetPrices 431 the value of rab. If the two investments are perfectly correlated, the combinations will lie along a straight line between the two points, since in this case both ERC and oRc will be linearly related to the proportions invested in the two plans. 11If they are less than perfectly positively correlated, the standard deviation of any combination must be less than that obtained with perfect correlation (since rabwill be less); thus the combinations must lie along a curve below the line AB. 2AZB shows such a curve for the case of complete independence (rab 0); with negative correlation the locus is even more U-shaped. 13 The manner in which the investment opportunity curve is formed is relatively simple conceptually, although exact solutions are usually quite difficult. 14 One first traces curves indicating ER, ORvalues available with simple combinations of individual assets, then considers combinations of combinations of assets. The lower right-hand boundary must be either linear or increasing at an increasing rate (d2 CR/dE2R; 0). As suggested earlier, the complexity of the relationship between the characteristics of individual assets and the location of the investment opportunity curve makes it difficult to provide a simple rule for assessing the desirability of individual assets, since the effect of an asset on an investors over-all investment opportunity curve depends not only on its expected rate of return (ERI) and risk (CR1), but also on its correlations with the other available opportunities (rii, rI2 . , rin). However, such a rule is implied by the equilibrium conditions for the model, as we will show in part IV. The Pure Rate of Interest We have not yet dealt with riskless assets. Let P be such an asset; its risk is zero (oRp = 0) and its expected rate of return, ERR, is equal (by definition) to the pure interest rate. If an investor places a of his wealth 11. ERC = aERa + (1 -a) ERb = ERb + (ERa ERb) butab a)2 cvRb2 + 2rab a(1 a) rRa aRb ORC= V/a2Ra2 + (1thereforethe expression underthe squareroot sign can be factored: 1, YRc = /[aaRa + (1 GO)cRb]2 a YRa + (1 (OYRa a) aRb 0Rb + YRb) a 12. This curvature is, in essence, the rationale for diversification. 13. When rab YRb ERbERa = 0, the slope of the curve at point A is ERb , at point B it is ERa . When rab =-1, the curve degeneratesto two straight lines to a point on the horizontal axis. 14. Markowitz has shown that this is a problem in parametricquadraticprogramming. An efficientsolution techniqueis describedin his article, The Optimizationof a Quadratic Function Subject to Linear Constraints,Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, Vol. 3 (March and June, 1956), 111-133. A solution method for a special case is given in the authorsA SimplifiedModel for Portfolio Analysis,op. cit. 432 The Journal of Finance in P and the remainderin some risky asset A, he would obtain an expected rate of return: ERC= aERP+ (1 a) ER1a The standard deviation of such a combination would be: 0Rc Va202Rp + ( -a)2aua2 + 2rpa a(1-a) (}RplRa but since ORp = 0, this reduces to: CrR = (1 a) (Ra. This implies that all combinations involving any risky asset or combination of assets plus the riskless asset must have values of ERC and OCR which lie along a straight line between the points representing the two components. Thus in Figure 4 all combinations of ER and OR lying along OaR P FIGURiE 4 v the line PA are attainable if some money is loaned at the pure rate and in some pBlaced A. Similarly, by lending at the pure rate and investing in combinations along PB can be attained. Of all such possibilities, howB, ever, one will dominate: that investment plan lying at the point of the curve where a ray from point P is tangent original investment opprortunity to the curve. In Figure 4 all investments lying along the original curve Capital Asset Prices 433 from X to cPare dominated by some combination of investment in 4 and lending at the pure interest rate. Consider next the possibility of borrowing. If the investor can borrow at the pure rate of interest, this is equivalent to disinvesting in P. The effect of borrowing to purchase more of any given investment than is possible with the given amount of wealth can be found simply by letting a take on negative values in the equations derived for the case of lending. This will obviously give points lying along the extension of line PA if borrowingis used to purchase more of A; points lying along the extension of PB if the funds are used to purchase B, etc. As in the case of lending, however, one investment plan will dominate all others when borrowing is possible. When the rate at which funds can be borrowedequals the lending rate, this plan will be the same one which is dominantif lending is to take place. Under these conditions, the investment opportunity curve becomes a line (POZ in Figure 4). Moreover, if the original investment opportunity curve is not linear at point c, the process of investment choice can be dichotomized as follows: first select the (unique) optimum combination of risky assets (point c), and second borrow or lend to obtain he particular point on PZ at which an indifference curve is tangent to the line. 5 Before proceeding with the analysis, it may be useful to consider alternative assumptions under which only a combination of assets lying at the point of tangency between the original investment opportunity curve and a ray from P can be efficient. Even if borrowingis impossible, the investor will choose 4 (and len ding) if his risk-aversion leads him to a point below 4)on the line Pq). Since a large number of investors choose to place some of their funds in relatively risk-free investments, this is not an unlikely possibility. Alternatively, if borrowing is possible but only up to some limit, the choice of 4) would be made by all but those investors willing to undertake considerablerisk. These alternative paths lead to the main conclusion, thus making the assumption of borrowing or lending at the pure interest rate less onerous than it might initially appear to be. III. IN EQUILIBRIUM THE CAPITAL MARKET In order to derive conditions for equilibrium in the capital market we invoke two assumptions. First, we assume a common pure rate of interest, with all investors able to borrow or lend funds on equal terms. Second, we assume homogeneity of investor expectations:16 investors are assumed 15. This proof was first presented by Tobin for the case in which the pure rate of interest is zero (cash). Hicks considersthe lending situation under comparableconditions but does not allow borrowing. Both authors present their analysis using maximization subject to constraints expressed as equalities. Hicks analysis assumes independenceand thus insures that the solution will include no negative holdings of risky assets; Tobins covers the general case, thus his solution would generally include negative holdings of some assets. The discussion in this paper is based on Markowitz formulation, which on includesnon-negativityconstraints the holdingsof all assets. 16. A term suggested by one of the referees. 434 The Journal of Finance to agree on the prospects of various investments-the expected values, standard deviations and correlation coefficients described in Part II. Needless to say, these are highly restrictive and undoubtedly unrealistic assumptions. However, since the proper test of a theory is not the realism of its assumptionsbut the acceptability of its implications,and since these assumptions imply equilibrium conditions which form a major part of classical financial doctrine, it is far from clear that this formulation should be rejected-especially in view of the dearth of alternative models leading to similar results. Under these assumptions, given some set of capital asset prices, each investor will view his alternatives in the same manner. For one set of prices the alternatives might appear as shown in Figure 5. In this situaaR Cl C2 -C3 C1/ / ~~ B B~2 1/ A3/ P FIGURE 5 ER tion an investor with the preferences indicated by indifferencecurves A1 throughA4 would seek to lend some of his funds at the pure interest rate and to invest the remainderin the combination of assets shown by point since this would give him the preferredover-all position A*. An investor 4,0 with the preferencesindicated by curves B1 through B4 would seek to invest all his funds in combination 4, while an investor with indifference curvesC1throughC4 would invest all his funds plus additional (borrowed) Capital Asset Prices 435 funds in combination 4 in order to reach his preferred position (C*). In any event, all would attempt to purchase only those risky assets which enter combination b. The attempts by investors to purchase the assets in combination 4 and their lack of interest in holding assets not in combination would, of course, lead to a revision of prices. The prices of assets in 4 will rise and, since an assets expected return relates future income to present price, their expected returns will fall. This will reduce the attractiveness of combinations which include such assets; thus point (among others) will move to the left of its initial position. 7 On the other hand, the prices of assets not in will fall, causing an increase in their expected returns and a rightwardmovement of points representingcombinationswhich include them. Such price changes will lead to a revision of investors actions; some new combination or combinations will become attractive, leading to different demandsand thus to further revisions in prices. As the process continues, the investment opp ortunity curve will tend to become more linear, with points such as moving to the left and formerly inefficient points (such as F and G) moving to the right. Capital asset prices must, of course, continue to change until a set of prices is attained for which every asset enters at least one combination lying on the capital market line. Figure 6 illustrates such an equilibrium condition. 8All possibilities in the shaded area can be attained with combinations of risky assets, while points lying along the line PZ can be attained by borrowing or lending at the pure rate plus an investment in some combination of risky assets. Certain possibilities (those lying along PZ from point A to point B) can be obtained in either manner. For example, the ER, aR values shown by point A can be obtained solely by some combination of risky assets; alternatively, the point can be reached by a combination of lending and investing in combination C of risky assets. It is important to recognize that in the situation shown in Figure 6 many alternative combinations of risky assets are efficient (i. e. , lie along line PZ), and thus the theory does not imply that all investors will hold On the same combination. 9 the other hand, all such combinations must be perfectly (positively) correlated,since they lie along a linear border of 17. If investors consider the variability of future dollar returns unrelated to present price, both ER and cR will fall; under these conditions the point representingan asset would move along a ray through the origin as its price changes. 18. The area in Figure 6 representingER aR values attained with only risky assets has been drawn at some distance from the horizontal axis for emphasis. It is likely that would place it very close to the axis. a more accurate representation 19. This statement contradicts Tobins conclusion that there will be a unique optimal combination of risky assets. Tobins proof of a unique optimum can be shown to be incorrect for the case of perfect correlation of efficient risky investment plans if the line connectingtheir ER, aR points would pass through point P. In the graph on page 83 of this article (op. cit. ) the constant-risklocus would, in this case, degenerate from a loci, thus giving family of ellipses into one of straight lines parallel to the constant-return multiple optima. 436 The Journalof Finance the ER, oR region. 20This provides a key to the relationship between the prices of capital assets and different types of risk. aRl B p FIGURE 6 ER IV. THE PRICES OF CAPITAL ASSETS We have argued that in equilibrium there will be a simple linear relationship between the expected return and standard deviation of return for efficient combinations of risky assets. Thus far nothing has been said about such a relationshipfor individualassets. Typically the ER,ORvalues associated with single assets will lie above the capital market line, reflecting the inefficiencyof undiversifiedholdings. Moreover, such points may be scattered throughout the feasible region, with no consistent relationship between their expected return and total risk (OR). However, there will be a consistent relationshipbetween their expected returns and what might best be called systematic risk, as we will now show. Figure 7 illustrates the typical relationship between a single capital 20. ER, 0R values given by combinations of any two combinationsmust lie within the region and cannot plot above a straightline joining the points. In this case they cannot plot below such a straight line. But since only in the case of perfect correlationwill they plot along a straight line, the two combinationsmust be perfectly correlated. As shown in Part IV, this does not necessarily imply that the individual securities they contain are perfectly correlated. Capital Asset Prices 437 asset (point i) and an efficient combination of assets (point g) of which oR it is a part. The curve igg indicates all ERJ, values which can be obtained with feasible combinations of asset i and combination g. As before, we denote such a combination in terms of a proportion a. of asset i and 1 would indicate pure investa) of combination g. A value of a (1 ?R _ P FiGuRE 7 ER ent in asset i while a = 0 would imply investment in combination g. Note, however, that a = . 5 implies a total investment of more than half the funds in asset i, since half would be invested in i itself and the other half used to purchase combination g, which also includes some of asset i. This means that a combinationin which asset i does not appear at all must be represented by some negative value of a. Point g indicates such a combination. In Figure 7 the curve igg has been drawn tangent to the capital market line (PZ) at point g. This is no accident. All such curves must be tangent to the capital market line in equilibrium,since (1) they must touch it at the point representing the efficient combination and (2) they are continuous at that point. 2 Under these conditions a lack of tangency would 21. Only if rig = -1 will the curve be discontinuousover the range in question. 438 The Journal of Finance imply that the curve intersects PZ. But then some feasible combinationof assets would lie to the right of the capital market line, an obvious impossibility since the capital market line represents the efficient boundary of feasible values of ER and OR. The requirement that curves such as igg be tangent to the capital market line can be shown to lead to a relatively simple formula which relates the expected rate of return to various elements of risk for all assets which are included in combinationg. 22Its economic meaning can best be seen if the relationship between the return of asset i and that of combination g is viewed in a manner similar to that used in regression analysis. 28Imagine that we were given a number of (ex post) observations of the return of the two investments. The points might plot as shown in Fig. . The scatter of the R, observations around their mean (which will approximate ERi) is, of course, evidence of the total risk of the asset CRi. But part of the scatter is due to an underlyingrelationshipwith the return on combination g, shown by Big, the slope of the regression line. The response of R, to changes in Rg (and variations in Rg itself) account for 22. The standard deviation of a combinationof g and i will be: or = V/a2aRi2 + (1 a)2 ORg2 + 2rig a(l a) cRiaRg at a = 0: do but or = 1 rjgcvRjaTgl daL = d[0Rg2 Rg at a = 0. Thus: da a [cvRg- rigaRil will be: The expectedreturnof a combination E = aERi + (1 ca) ERg Thus, at all values of a: dE dL = _ [ERg ERJ] and, at a = 0: dcv cvRg- rigcfRi dE ERg-ERi Let the equationof the capitalmarketline be: CvR = S(ER P) = where P is the pure interest rate. Since igg is tangent to the line when c lies on the line: (ERg, CvRg) qp,Rg~- jgj dR rigq. ,i Rg ERgERi ERg P 0, and since or: E rgRE l+ LERg ERi. -P] [ERg-P 23. This model has been called the diagonal model since its portfolio analysis solution can be facilitated by re-arranging data so that the variance-covariance the matrix becomes diagonal. The method is described in the authors article, cited earlier. CapitalAssetPrices Return on Asset i (Ri) 439 . , ~~~ig -4.. ERi Return FIGuRE8 on Combination g (Rg) much of the variation in Ri. It is this component of the assets total risk which we term the systematic risk. The remainder,24 being uncorrelated with Rg, is the unsystematic component. This formulation of the relationship between R, and Rg can be employed ex ante as a predictive model. Big becomes the predicted response of Ri to changes in Rg. Then, given ORg (the predicted risk of Rg), the systematic portion of the predicted risk of each asset can be determined. This interpretation allows us to state the relationship derived from the tangency of curves such as igg with the capital market line in the form shown in Figure 9. All assets entering efficient combination g must have (predicted) Big and ER, values lying on the line PQ. 25Prices will 24. ex post, the standarderror. 25. /Big20 Rg2 g BigcRg ORi aRi2 and: Big =- -rigcvRi 4 oRg The expressionon the right is the expressionon the left-hand side of the last equation in footnote 22. Thus: Big = E- Rg P + [EgiP] ERI. 440 The Journal of Finance djust so that assets which are more responsive to changes in Rg will have higher expected returns than those which are less responsive. This accords with common sense. Obviously the part of an assets risk which is due to its correlationwith the return on a combinationcannot be diversifiedaway when the asset is added to the combination. Since Bigindicates the magnitude of this type of risk it should be directly related to expected return. The relationsh ipillustrated in Figure 9 provides a partial answer to the question posed earlier concerning the relationship between an assets risk Q Big 0 J______________ t -f Pure Rate of Interest -P ~~~~~~~~~~E FIGURE 9 and its expected return. But thus far we have argued only that the relationship holds for the assets which enter some particular efficient combination (g). Had another combination been selected, a different linear relationshipwould have been derived. Fortunately this limitation is easily overcome. As shown in the footnote,26 we may arbitrarily select any one 26. Consider the two assets i and i*, the former included in efficient combination g and the latter in combinationg*. As shown above: Big = -[E1,gP] and: + [E P] ERI Capital Asset Prices 441 of the efficient combinations, then measure the predicted responsiveness of every assets rate of return to that of the combination selected; and these coefficients will be related to the expected rates of return of the assets in exactly the mannerpictured in Figure 9. The fact that rates of return from all efficient combinations will be perfectly correlatedprovides the justification for arbitrarily selecting any one of them. Alternatively we may choose instead any variable perfectly correlated with the rate of return of such combinations. The vertical axis in Figure 9 would then indicate alternative levels of a coefficient measuring the sensitivity of the rate of return of a capital asset to changes in the variable chosen. This possibility suggests both a plausible explanation for the implication that all efficient combinations will be perfectly correlated and a useful interpretation of the relationship between an individual assets expected return and its risk. Although the theory itself implies only that rates of return from efficient combinations will be perfectly correlated, we might expect that this would be due to their common dependence on the over-all level of economic activity. If so, diversification enables the investor to escape all but the risk resulting from swings in economic activity-this type of risk remains even in efficient combinations. And, since all other types can be avoided by diversification, only the responsiveness of an assets rate of return to the level of economic activity is relevant in BJ*g* = rj*g* = rj*g Thus: Bi*g*oRg* Bi*gcrRg [ERg* P + [E *-P] ER11* Since Rg and Rg* are perfectly correlated: and: B. = Bi*g[ [ ORg Crjg Since both g and g* lie on a line which intercepts the E-axis at P: YRg ERg-P ERg* P and: (yRg* Bj*g* = Bi*g P Thus: [E g p] ERi* = Bi*g from which we have the desired relationship between R,* and g: [ ]ER:P + [ E Pz] Bj*g[] ErP+ [El IP] Bi*g must therefore plot on the same line as does Big. 442 The Journal of Finance assessing its risk. Prices will adjust until there is a linear relationship between the magnitude of such responsiveness and expected return. Assets which are unaffected by changes in economic activity will return the pure interest rate; those which move with economic activity will promise appropriatelyhigher expected rates of return. This discussion provides an answer to the second of the two questions posed in this paper. In Part III it was shown that with respect to equilibrium conditions in the capital market as a whole, the theory leads to results consistent with classical doctrine (i. e. , the capital market line). We have now shown that with regard to capital assets considered individually, it also yields implications consistent with traditional concepts: it is commonpractice for investment counselorsto accept a lower expected return from defensive securities (those which respond little to changes in the economy) than they require from aggressive securities (which exhibit significant response). As suggested earlier, the familiarity of the implications need not be considereda drawback. The provision of a logical framework for producing some of the major elements of traditional financial theory should be a useful contributionin its own right.

No comments:

Post a Comment

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.